CIPFA Scotland Annual Conference 2013:
‘Edge of chaos: leading to new possibilities’
Paul Cairney, Professor of
Politics and Public Policy, University of Stirling p.a.cairney@stir.ac.uk
Complexity Theory and Complex Adaptive Systems
The theme running through this
year’s conference is: ‘adaptive system thinking … how adaptive public finance
and its finance function and people are’.
There are three key sources of background for the discussions:
-
Economic crisis. The UK and devolved governments are addressing a new age of austerity associated with economic crisis, rising government debt and plans to reduce public spending. The reductions may be so significant, in some areas, that they prompt a complete rethink of the way that governments plan and deliver services (or new ways to identify, understand and seek to solve policy problems). In some areas, governments may simply cut budgets and encourage other bodies to decide how to adapt.
- Targets and rules. How can targets and rules ensure the delivery of public services? This is a perennial topic in the study of government. For CIPFA in particular, the issue may relate to the need to follow rules to ensure that the spending of public money is properly accounted for. We may ask ourselves if current rules and targets produce the right sort of behaviour or if they encourage rigid rule following (or game playing) which might cause unintended consequences.
- Organisational Change in Scotland. Since 2007, the Scottish Government has made some important changes to the Scottish public sector – centralising some areas (such as the police and fire services) and decentralising others (such as local authorities). Its new relationship with local authorities has the potential to place more responsibility on local actors to identify and solve problems rather than implement policies made from the ‘top’. The Scottish Government’s approach may also be contrasted with that of the UK Government (associated with a more extensive and punitive targets/ inspection regime).
A combination of all three elements
draws our attention to the importance of adapting and responding to crises,
perhaps by taking a flexible approach to existing rules to ensure that they are
not overtaken by events and new problems. Such decisions may increasingly be
taken at a local level, often without central government direction; they may
fall increasingly to particular branches or professions within larger
governmental organisations, often without explicit or detailed government
direction. This is a situation that may
be particularly worrying to a profession built on demonstrating financial accountability
to the public through government and Parliament.
In this context, one aim of the
conference is to find the right balance between following proper rules properly
and adopting a flexible approach: to use discretion to secure outcomes for
which policies may have been designed; and, to interpret rules in the right way
to secure the right outcomes. This
process is subject to uncertainty; it is difficult to know how to use rules
flexibly. Indeed, even the language we
might use to describe it – such as ‘stretching’ rules – implies that it is
inappropriate. So, while most of the
sessions are devoted to how accountants and other actors in the public sector
might become more creative in their contribution to the use of public money,
this blog (and my first brief lecture) is devoted simply to the question: how
can we justify the flexible use of government rules?
If put bluntly, the main message
that we could take from the
policymaking literature is that:
-
No government can control the public sector, its outputs or the subsequent outcomes.
- Many governments exacerbate this problem by imposing a large number of too-rigid targets backed up by a punitive inspection regime, producing unintended consequences.
- Giving more discretion to local public sector employees allows them to adapt to local circumstances in a way that central governments cannot anticipate.
A classic discussion of this
problem can be linked to key texts in the policymaking literature, including:
-
Lipsky’s idea of ‘street level bureaucracy’. He suggests that there are so many targets, rules and laws that no public agency or official can be reasonably expected to fulfil them all. In fact, many may be too vague or even contradictory, requiring ‘street level bureaucrats’ to choose some over others. The potential irony is that the cumulative pressure from more central government rules and targets effectively provides implementers with a greater degree of freedom to manage their budgets and day-to-day activities.
- Hjern’s focus on intra-departmental conflict, when central government departments pursue programmes with competing aims, and interdependence, when policies are implemented by multiple organizations. Programmes are implemented through ‘implementation structures’ where ‘parts of many public and private organizations cooperate in the implementation of a programme’. Although national governments create the overall framework of regulations and resources, and there are ‘administrative imperatives’ behind the legislation authorizing a programme, the main shaping of policy takes place at local levels.
- The more recent focus on ‘governance’ as an alternative to the idea of ‘government’ (not to be confused with a discussion of ‘corporate’ or ‘good’ governance). While such problems of central government control have prompted governments in the past to embrace New Public Management (NPM) and seek to impose order through hierarchy and targeting, local implementation networks (with members from the public, third and private sectors) may not be amenable to such direct control
A more recent contribution comes
from the modern study of complexity theory.
As Marco Thiel’s discussion on Friday suggests, complexity theory has
been applied to an incredibly wide range of activity, from the swarming
behaviour of bees, the weather and the function of the brain, to social and
political systems. The argument is that
all such systems have common properties or are subject to the same arguments,
including:
-
A complex system is greater than the sum of its parts; those parts are interdependent - elements interact with each other, share information and combine to produce systemic behaviour.
- Some attempts to influence complex systems are dampened (negative feedback) while others are amplified (positive feedback). Small actions can have large effects and large actions can have small effects.
- Complex systems are particularly sensitive to initial conditions that produce a long-term momentum or ‘path dependence’.
- They exhibit ‘emergence’, or behaviour that results from the interaction between elements at a local level rather than central direction.
- They may contain ‘strange attractors’ or demonstrate extended regularities of behaviour which may be interrupted by short bursts of change.
As you might expect from (what
seems like) a theory of all things, the language is vague and needs some
interpretation in each field. In the policymaking field, the identification of
a complex system is often used to make the following suggestions:
-
Law-like behaviour is difficult to identify – so a policy that was successful in one context may not have the same effect in another.
- Policymaking systems are difficult to control; policy makers should not be surprised when their policy interventions do not have the desired effect.
- Policy makers in the UK have been too driven by the idea of order, maintaining rigid hierarchies and producing top-down, centrally driven policy strategies. An attachment to performance indicators, to monitor and control local actors, may simply result in policy failure and demoralised policymakers.
- Policymaking systems or their environments change quickly. Therefore, organisations must adapt quickly and not rely on a single policy strategy.
On this basis, there is a
tendency in the literature to encourage the delegation of decision-making to
local actors:
-
Rely less on central government driven targets, in favour of giving local organisations more freedom to learn from their experience and adapt to their rapidly-changing environment.
- To deal with uncertainty and change, encourage trial-and-error projects, or pilots, that can provide lessons, or be adopted or rejected, relatively quickly.
- Encourage better ways to deal with alleged failure by treating ‘errors’ as sources of learning (rather than a means to punish organisations) or setting more realistic parameters for success/ failure.
- Encourage a greater understanding, within the public sector, of the implications of complex systems and terms such as ‘emergence’ or ‘feedback loops’.
In other words, this literature,
when applied to policymaking, tends to encourage a movement from centrally
driven targets, rules and performance indicators towards a more flexible
understanding of rules and targets by local actors who are more able to
understand and adapt to rapidly-changing local circumstances.
Of course, you may still end up
feeling that the advice is a bit vague (and perhaps not completely convincing),
but it provides a starting point for discussion, followed by various conference
presentations on how to use, creatively or flexibly, new forms of discretion in
the public sector. There will be the
usual forums for participation – including Q&A sessions after lectures and
smaller seminar groups – as well as a live twitter feed throughout (#cipfascotlandconference).
Cairney, P. (2012) ‘Complexity
Theory in Political Science and Public Policy’, Political Studies Review, 10,
346-58 http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1478-9302.2012.00270.x/abstract
(or email Paul for a copy)