I am writing a paper about the ability of policy scholars to describe
and explain policymaking in a way that is understandable to policymakers and
practitioners (it will appear here and here). The background discussion is about the extent to which there is
too much jargon in the literature. If so, it may act as a barrier to meaningful
discussions between academics and policymakers (which may be seen as
particularly problematic in this new age of academic ‘impact’). The paper
suggests that many academic insights are useful, as a basis for discussion with
policymakers, if we take the time to discuss them together.
The aim of this post is a bit different: to see if I can summarise and translate
the concepts to the readers of the post *without* any discussion! I will do it
by removing almost all of the jargon from the paper (which often means more
words – the jargon is a useful shorthand). I think that this task is made much
easier by the slow trickle of these ideas into the public consciousness. For
example, one conclusion you can take from the discussion is that a change of
party in government does not produce a massive change in policy. This is
something that you tend to hear in public discussions (although I admit that
the discussions may not draw much from policy theory). So, I will continue this
theme, by outlining some common phrases (associated largely with the pathology
of policymaking) and using policy theory to help explain them in a way that
might, in some cases, make the whole business of government a bit less
disheartening. Or, I will make up these phrases for effect. Definitely one or
the other. I will also put those phrases in capital letters, so that you can
imagine them being shouted by someone looking for attention.
IT’S ALWAYS SOMEONE ELSE’S FAULT – NO ONE EVER TAKES THE BLAME.
I think that you can divide this sort of frustration into two main
parts: ministers generally don’t take the blame for things going wrong; and/ or
no-one seems to get the blame for something going wrong in individual cases
(such as in cases of child cruelty or hospital mismanagement).
The argument with ministers is so strong because we support the idea
that governments are accountable to the public via Parliament. So, ministers
are in charge and they report to Parliament. Or, they get a telling-off from
Jeremy Paxman on Newsnight. Yet, ministers have two good reasons not to take
the blame.
First, policy is often now made at many levels (and types) of
government. For example, something like ‘tobacco policy’ is actually a
collection of policies made by the European Union, UK and, in some cases,
devolved governments (and sometimes local authorities). Policy is also often
carried out by a range of bodies which often operate at ‘arms length’ from
ministers. In some cases, this looks like ministers are simply passing the buck
to other bodies, to avoid making controversial decisions. In others, there is
good reason to maintain these arrangements. My favourite example is in mental
health where there are arms-length bodies there to make sure that doctors and
social workers use the Mental Health Act correctly when they ‘section’ people.
Those bodies have to exert a degree of independence to assure the public that
they are not simply there to back up the decisions of others.
The outcome of these multi-level and arms-length arrangements is that
ministers cannot simply make policy. Instead, they are increasingly obliged to
negotiate policy with a wide range of other bodies.
The second defence for ministers is that they cannot pay attention to all
of the issues for which they are responsible. In fact, they can only pay
attention to a tiny proportion – which makes it entirely plausible for them to
look shocked when a decision, made in their name, has gone badly. This is also
why regular changes of government do not cause wholesale shifts in policy:
most decisions are beyond the reach of ministers. The sheer size of government means that it
could easily become unmanageable. So, governments break policy down into more
manageable departments, and a large number of divisions within departments,
dealing with issues that involve a smaller number of knowledgeable
participants. Most policy is made at a
level of government not particularly visible to the public or Parliament, and
with minimal ministerial or senior civil service involvement. These arrangements exist because there is a
logic to devolving decisions and consulting with certain groups. Ministers rely on their officials for
information and advice. For specialist
issues, those officials rely on specialist organisations. Organisations trade that information and
advice (and other things, such as the ability to generate agreement among large
and influential groups) for access to, and influence within, government.
Ministers are *responsible* for this activity, and they can set the tone of
many of the debates, but they cannot pay attention to everything going on. In
fact, paying attention to one issue means ignoring most others. So, that look
of permanent befuddlement on Newsnight may be entirely understandable.
The other sort of problem relates to things going wrong in local
and health authorities when, for example, a child is not protected or a patient
is treated badly while in care. Organisations hold inquiries and learn lessons
but no one is necessarily strung up and blamed for the problem. The defence in
this case is that public sector professionals do not have the ability to carry
out all of their responsibilities. They are subject to such a wide range of
rules, regulations and expectations from government that they cannot pay
attention to them all (I tend to think of this comic strip, but it’s not that
bad - http://dilbert.com/strips/comic/1995-06-25/)
. Instead, they use their judgement to satisfy an adequate proportion of
government objectives. As a result, things go wrong and we find that some
people or organisations did not carry out government policy. In these cases, it
is not easy to blame an organisation – they *have* to ignore some directions to
make sure that they follow others. It is also difficult to blame ministers,
because the chances are that they already have policies in place to deal with
these sorts of things – they just weren’t carried out.
IT’S ONE IDEA AFTER ANOTHER WITH THIS GOVERNMENT – THEY HAVE THE
ATTENTION SPAN OF A GNAT …
The explanation for this practice is quite similar: policymakers can only pay attention to a
small number of the issues for which they are responsible. So, they ignore most and promote a few to the
top of their agenda, often following a major event or a successful media
campaign by certain groups. So, for every issue to which ministers (and senior
civil servants) pay attention, they must ignore (say) 99 others. The tendency to focus on that one issue
*might* produce major policy change when, for example, so much pressure is
required to get ministerial attention that, when they do, it is a bit like a
dam busting; a wide range of people get involved to influence policy in a short
space of time. However, the logical
consequence to their attention to that one issue is that the same thing does
not happen in most other cases. In most cases, it is business as usual, since
so much policymaking is devolved to people who operate out of the public and
political spotlight.
… AND YET NOTHING EVER CHANGES.
I said that this concentrated attention on some issues *might* change
things because it also might not. There are four main reasons to expect less
than radical change following these bursts of attention. First, people might
find that there is no easy solution to the problem receiving so much attention.
Good, sensible, acceptable solutions take time to develop and it is possible
for public and ministerial attention to lurch to another issue before this
problem is solved (or at least solved to the satisfaction of policymakers and
influential groups). Indeed, as silly as it sounds, a key feature of
policymaking is that the solution to a problem may be devised *before* there is
significant attention to the problem. Second, policymakers do not have the
brain power or resources to consider all options and the consequences of their
policies. So, many rely on trial-and-error policymaking or depart from
current policy in a series of steps. For policymakers, this has the added
benefit of reduced controversy: radical policy change always produces winners
and losers; a government could try to impose its will, but this can be
politically expensive and governments can only spend so much. Third,
governments inherit policy before they choose. Any ‘new’ policy is likely to be
a revision of an old one, perhaps following some degree of failure. They might
want to make serious changes, but they are also constrained by decisions made
by governments in the past – decisions that produce organisations, rules,
regulations and employees that are difficult to remove.
Finally, things don’t change overnight because people’s beliefs don’t
change overnight. In most cases, policymakers ‘learn’ from their experience
(which includes their mistakes) but their learning is influenced heavily by the
way that they understand the world. Or, in a wider sense, there may be a
particular understanding of the policy problem, and its solution, that is
promoted by a wide range of powerful groups. Events may draw attention to
policy problems without changing that balance of power or the fundamental
beliefs of those involved. Maybe the most obvious example just now is the
banking crisis which produced some changes but not radical change in the way
that governments treat the financial sector – but the same point could be made
whenever we see crises in areas such as health or education.
WHY DO I FEEL POWERLESS?
The final point to remember is that the study of policy is the study of
power: the relatively powerful and the relatively powerless; the winners and
the losers. Importantly, power is not simply about visible conflicts in which
one group wins and another loses. Rather, it can take at least two other
important forms. First, groups may exercise power to reinforce social
attitudes. If the weight of public opinion is against government action, maybe
governments will not intervene. The classic example is poverty – if most people
believe that it is caused by fecklessness, what is the role of government? In
such cases, power and powerlessness may relate to the (in)ability of groups to
persuade the public, media and/ or government that there is a reason to make
policy; a problem to be solved. In other
examples, the battle may be about the extent to which issues are private (with
no legitimate role for government) or public (and open to legitimate government
action), including: should governments intervene in disputes between businesses
and workers? Should they intervene in disputes between husbands and wives?
Should they try to stop people smoking in places that might be considered
private or public? If you reached this blog via twitter, you will be very
familiar with how this process looks in practice: people make policy
suggestions, they receive some support, then they receive an absolute barrage
of criticism, and often abuse, by others. In this context, groups may be
powerful if they are able to reinforce the anti-policy-change attitudes already
held by many people.
Second, groups may exercise other forms of power to keep an issue off
the government agenda. As I said above, policymakers can only pay attention to
a tiny amount of issues for which they are responsible. So, groups may exercise
power to keep some issues on their agenda at the expense of others. Issues on the agenda are sometimes described
as ‘safe’ – more attention to these issues means less attention to the
imbalances of power within society. Again, if you are a follower of twitter,
you may get the impression that people pay attention to nothing but safe issues
for a few seconds at a time. I’m afraid I can’t do anything to make *that* seem
less dispiriting.